Supermodular function

In mathematics, a function

is supermodular if

for all x, y Rk, where x y denotes the componentwise maximum and x y the componentwise minimum of x and y.

If f is supermodular then f is called submodular, and if the inequality is changed to an equality the function is modular.

If f is twice continuously differentiable, then supermodularity is equivalent to the condition[1]

Supermodularity in economics and game theory

The concept of supermodularity is used in the social sciences to analyze how one agent's decision affects the incentives of others.

Consider a symmetric game with a smooth payoff function defined over actions of two or more players . Suppose the action space is continuous; for simplicity, suppose each action is chosen from an interval: . In this context, supermodularity of implies that an increase in player 's choice increases the marginal payoff of action for all other players . That is, if any player chooses a higher , all other players have an incentive to raise their choices too. Following the terminology of Bulow, Geanakoplos, and Klemperer (1985), economists call this situation strategic complementarity, because players' strategies are complements to each other.[2] This is the basic property underlying examples of multiple equilibria in coordination games.[3]

The opposite case of submodularity of corresponds to the situation of strategic substitutability. An increase in lowers the marginal payoff to all other player's choices , so strategies are substitutes. That is, if chooses a higher , other players have an incentive to pick a lower .

For example, Bulow et al. consider the interactions of many imperfectly competitive firms. When an increase in output by one firm raises the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic complements. When an increase in output by one firm lowers the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic substitutes.


A supermodular utility function is often related to complementary goods. However, this view is disputed.[4]

Supermodular functions of subsets

Supermodularity and submodularity are also defined for functions defined over subsets of a larger set. Intuitively, a submodular function over the subsets demonstrates "diminishing returns". There are specialized techniques for optimizing submodular functions.

Let S be a finite set. A function is supermodular if for any and , . For submodularity, the inequality is reversed.

The definition of supermodularity can equivalently be formulated as

for all subsets A and B of S.

See also

Notes and references

  1. The equivalence between the definition of supermodularity and its calculus formulation is sometimes called Topkis' Characterization Theorem. See Paul Milgrom and John Roberts (1990), 'Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities', Econometrica 58 (6), page 1261.
  2. Jeremy I. Bulow, John D. Geanakoplos, and Paul D. Klemperer (1985), 'Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and strategic complements'. Journal of Political Economy 93, pp. 488511.
  3. Russell Cooper and Andrew John (1988), 'Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models.' Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 (3), pp. 44163.
  4. Chambers, Christopher P.; Echenique, Federico (2009). "Supermodularity and preferences". Journal of Economic Theory. 144 (3): 1004. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2008.06.004.

External links

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 6/7/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.