Gustav von Schmoller

Gustav von Schmoller

Gustav von Schmoller by Nicola Perscheid c. 1908
Born (1838-06-24)24 June 1838
Heilbronn, Germany
Died 27 June 1917(1917-06-27) (aged 79)
Bad Harzburg, Germany
Nationality German
Field Economics
School or
tradition
Historical school of economics
Influences Karl Wolfgang Christoph Schüz
Influenced Werner Sombart
Thorstein Veblen
Joseph Schumpeter
Max Sering
Edwin Francis Gay

Gustav von Schmoller (German: [ˈʃmɔlɐ]; 24 June 1838 – 27 June 1917) was the leader of the "younger" German historical school of economics.

Life

Schmoller was born in Heilbronn. His father was a Württemberg civil servant. Young Schmoller studied Staatswissenschaften (a combination of economics, law, history, and civil administration) at the University of Tübingen (1857–61). In 1861, he obtained an appointment at the Württemberg Statistical Department.[1] During his academic career, he held appointments as a professor at the universities of Halle (1864–72), Strasbourg (1872–82), and Berlin (1882–1913).[2] After 1899, he represented the University of Berlin in the Prussian House of Lords. He was a leading Sozialpolitiker (more derisively, Kathedersozialist, "Socialist of the Chair"), and a founder and long-time chairman of the Verein für Socialpolitik, the German Economic Association, which continues to exist.[3] Schmoller's influence on academic policy, economic, social and fiscal reform, and economics as an academic discipline for the time between 1875 and 1910[4] can hardly be overrated. He was also an outspoken proponent of the assertion of German naval power and the expansion of the German overseas empire.

Work

Untersuchungen über das Methode der socialwissenschaften und der politischen Ökonomie insbesondere, 1933

As an outspoken leader of the "younger" historical school, Schmoller opposed what he saw as the axiomatic-deductive approach of classical economics and, later, the Austrian school—indeed, Schmoller coined the term to suggest provincialism in an unfavorable review of the 1883 book Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics (Untersuchungen über die Methode der Socialwissenschaften und der politischen Oekonomie insbesondere) by Carl Menger, which attacked the methods of the historical school. This led to the controversy known as the Methodenstreit, which today often appears as a waste of energies and one of the main reasons for the later demise of the whole historical school, although—as Joseph Schumpeter once pointed out—this was really a quarrel within that school. Schmoller's primarily inductive approach, requesting careful study, comparative in time and space,[4] of economic performance and phenomena generally, his focus on the evolution of economic processes and institutions, and his insistence on the cultural specificity of economics and the centrality of values in shaping economic exchanges stand in stark contrast to some classical and most neoclassical economists, so that he and his school fell out of the mainstream of economics by the 1930s, being replaced in Germany by the successor Freiburg school.

However, it is often overlooked that Schmoller's primary preoccupation in his lifetime was not with economic method but with economic and social policy to address the challenges posed by rapid industrialization and urbanization. That is, Schmoller was first and foremost a social reformer.[5] As such, Schmoller's influence extended throughout Europe, to the Progressive movement in the United States, and to social reformers in Meiji Japan. His most prominent non-German students and followers included William J. Ashley, W.E.B. Du Bois, Richard T. Ely, Noburu Kanai, Albion W. Small, and E.R.A. Seligman.

Since the 1980s, Schmoller's work has been re-evaluated and found relevant to some branches of heterodox economics, especially development economics, behavioral economics, evolutionary economics, and neo-institutional economics. He has long had an influence within the subfield of economic history and the discipline of sociology.

Works by Schmoller

His works, the majority of which deal with economic history and policy, include:

After 1881, Schmoller was editor of the Jahrbuch für Gesetzebung, Verwaltung, und Volkswirthschaft im deutschen Reich. From 1878 to 1903, he edited a series of monographs entitled Staats- und sozialwissenschaftliche Forschungen. He was also an editor and major contributor to Acta Borussica, an extensive collection of Prussian historical sources undertaken by the Berlin Academy of Science upon Schmoller's and Sybel's instigation.

One of the reasons why Schmoller is not more widely known today is that most of his books and articles were not translated,[3] as during his time Anglo-American economists generally read German, which was the dominant scholarly language of the time. German having fallen out of favor, the untranslated texts are now inaccessible to readers without knowledge of German. Two exceptions are:

His magnum opus is

Important recent books on Schmoller in English

See also

Notes

  1.  Chisholm, Hugh, ed. (1911). "Schmoller, Gustav". Encyclopædia Britannica (11th ed.). Cambridge University Press.
  2. Encyclopedia of Law and Society: American and Global Perspectives, 3rd ed., “Schmoller, Gustav von.”
  3. 1 2 3 Bonn, M.J. (1938). "Gustav Schmoller und die Volkswirtschaftslehre". The Economic Journal. 48 (192): 713. doi:10.2307/2225060. JSTOR 2225060.
  4. 1 2 Powers, Charles H. (1995). "Review". American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 54 (3): 287–288. JSTOR 3487093.
  5. Grimmer-Solem, Erik (2003) The Rise of Historical Economics and Social Reform in Germany, 1864–1894 (Oxford: Oxford University Press.

References

Wikimedia Commons has media related to Gustav Schmoller.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 11/13/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.